areppim: information, pure and simple

areppim: information, pure and simple


You are here:   areppim >  Corruption & Inequality >  Corruption Index Trends - 2018

Corruption Index Trends


areppim line chart and statistics of CPI (corruption perceptions index) median, highest and lowest scores from 1995 to 2018. The index distribution has shifted towards the lower end of the scale along the 24-year period in the chart, exposing the generalized sliding towards a more corrupt environment. The shift affects all countries, including the least corrupt ones, revealing an ongoing albeit slow moral deterioration. The long term trend of the median index heralds loud and clear the triumph of corruption and the decay of probity across the planet.

 

TI's (Transparency International) CPI (Corruption Perception Index) for 2018 opens with a candid acknowledgement.

More than two-thirds of countries score below 50 on this year's CPI, with an average score of just 43. It reveals that the continued failure of most countries to significantly control corruption is contributing to a crisis in democracy around the world. While there are exceptions, the data shows that despite some progress, most countries are failing to make serious inroads against corruption.

Simple arithmetics validate TI's assessment, although one may take exception of the conclusion. It is improper to say that corruption contributes to a crisis in democracy. More befittingly, corruption fosters pervasive social anomie — the disintegration of social ties, norms and values —, be it in democracies, pseudo-democracies, oligarchies, theocracies or outright tyrannies. TI's obstinacy to stick to their good, old opinions about the why's and the then what's of corruption is perplexing. How come that several decades-long records of steadfast probity decline do not suffice to lead them to explore other avenues?

Yes, make no mistake, corruption keeps carrying on, as unflinching as a Swiss clockwork, bearing witness of the specious ingenuity of the white knights whose willingness to spout anti-corruption balderdash on us is commensurate only with their resolution to serve their personal interests first.

Indeed, the preposterous anti-corruption bravado of statesmen, high public officials, international civil servants, and, not to be overlooked, the righteous fellows of the non-governmental organizations dedicated to fight corruption, all their bombast has only driven perceived probity downwards worldwide, year after year. Since 1995, perceived corruption among public officials and politicians has gone down. The median score sank at the annual average rate of 1.69%, while the lowest score dropped at the annual rate of 2.84%. The best-in-class themselves, the virtuous Scandinavian countries and New Zealand, fell 0.35% per year.

The big question is what purpose serve the alleged efforts by the States, the OECD, the World Bank, the Specialized Agencies of the United Nations, and the hyperactive ONGs to curb the corruption evil? If their jurists, legislators, law-enforcement bodies, regulatory committees, norm-setting panels and moral peddlers cannot achieve a higher performance, then anybody in the street could advise them that they got it all wrong, and they would better ponder a radical change of strategy. Provided of course that there is a drop of sincerity in their discourse.

Let us assume for a moment that they are neither downright mendacious, nor utterly dumb. They should be thankful that someone tells them about the two big flaws of their current approaches.

Number one, they address corruption as an individual flaw, a disease that affects individual persons as such, a malady that could be treated by the behaviorist method, the appropriate mix of reward and punishment, in an hygienic environment of efficient surveillance and control. Hence the array of legislative acts, administrative gateways, and convoluted procedures that the white knights set up to make life miserable for the corrupt. The outcome is contemptible. The public understands that they are out to kill an elephant with a fly gun. They may catch the small fry all right, but they do not come close to start clearing the ranks of the big game. Realistically, everybody says that corruption is getting worse every year.

No matter what the white knights believe, corruption is not an individual issue, but a social one. While alone in his island, Robinson Crusoe cannot commit any act of corruption. He needs other people from whom to take advantage by means of manipulation, deceit, misleading, tricking. There comes his companion Friday that Robinson rescues from the cannibals. This initial good deed opens the door. By promises of protection and by preaching the good Christian faith, Robinson has now a slave for free, a genuine man Friday. He can now rest from the hardships of extenuating work. The embryo of corruption is complete with its two components: an initial favor, and the subsequent payback. From then on, it is a matter of circumstances. Darwinism explains that the struggle for survival of the fittest will rule the behavior of our heroes. The greediness to seize the good opportunity, the urge to escape from the threat, the inherited or the acquired ability to adapt will map the trail ahead. Laws and administrative procedures are as useless to control the process, as they would be to impose any traffic regulations upon bacteria and white blood cells engaged in a race for survival. The white knights, raised in the neo-liberal, neo-darwinistic ideologies must know that. But like the drunkard searching his lost key in the dark, they do what they know how to, not what the situation demands. They probably think that it helps their own struggle for life — in the short run, it likely will.

The second failure is that, without exception that we are aware of, the arsenal of anti-corruption initiatives are directed towards managing, not extirpating the evil. In other words, they aim at unbalancing the cost-benefit ratio, by rendering the cost of corruption unacceptably high for its benefits, by increasing its risks, thus causing the optimization of the benefits of corruption more problematic. The white knights do not really strive to suppress corruption, only to bridle it to the point of making its social cost more affordable.

It is a waste. Corrupters will bounce back, devising new ways to counter the attacks, adapting to the new prevailing market circumstances. We are not dealing with a mechanic contraption, with a scale that can be set in equilibrium by carefully balancing the weights in its plates. Like all other social phenomena, it is an open system with feedback loops. Think of bacterial infections. Antibiotics are typically used to treat them with success. However in recent years, we have witnessed the spread of several strains of antibiotic-resistant bacteria. Infectious bacteria are no longer susceptible to previously effective antibiotics. Similarly, the corruption virus will strike back harder and trickier.

To cut it short, it is a hopeless fight, right? Not so fast! As long as the powers that be ignore corruption as a social phenomenon and as a living open system, as long as they regard people as behavioristic pigeons, deprived of conscience, commanded by pain and pleasure only, surely corruption will flourish. After all, as the classic Greek and Roman chroniclers report, it has been around since the beginnings of the European civilization, not to mention more remote epochs and places. However, as the same authors tell, there were also persons, not Skinner pigeons, with a conscience, and with an idea of a different world, where togetherness, fairness and independence would render corruption an obsolete and repugnant oddity. They still exist today and the fight goes on.

 

Corruption Perceptions Index ¹

1995 - 2018
Median, Maximum & Minimum scores

YearMedianMaximumMinimum
199556.295.50New Zealand19.4Indonesia
199650.1594.30New Zealand6.9Nigeria
199752.2599.40Denmark17.6Nigeria
199842100.00Denmark14Cameroon
199938100.00Denmark15Cameroon
200041100.00Finland12Nigeria
20014099.00Finland4Bangladesh
200237.597.00Finland12Bangladesh
20033497.00Finland13Bangladesh
200433.597.00Finland15Bangladesh
20053297.00Iceland17Bangladesh
20063296.00Finland18Haiti
20073394.00Denmark14Myanmar
20083493.00Denmark10Somalia
20093394.00New Zealand11Somalia
20103393.00Denmark, New Zealand, Singapore11Somalia
20113295.00New Zealand10Korea DPR, Somalia
20123790.00Denmark,Finland,New Zealand8Afghanistan, Korea, D.P.R of, Somalia
20133891.00Denmark,New Zealand8Afghanistan, Korea, D.P.R of, Somalia
20143892.00Denmark8Korea, D.P.R of, Somalia
20153791.00Denmark8Korea, D.P.R of, Somalia
20163890.00Denmark, New Zealand10Somalia
201838.589.00New Zealand9Somalia
20183888Denmark10Somalia
Average annual change rate-1.69%-0.35% -2.84% 
Slope of the regression line-0.5-0.45 -0.26 
 ¹ The Corruption Perceptions Index ranks countries in terms of the degree to which corruption is perceived to exist among public officials and politicians. The country with the lowest score is the one where corruption is perceived to be greatest. Browse the complete Corruption Perceptions Index lists from 1995.
 ² The scale 0 to 10 became 0 to 100 in 2012. For charting and computation purposes, data points from 2012 onwards have been adjusted by dividing by 10.

 

 Download,  Download

Sources: Transparency International.